http://naxalrevolution.googlepages.com/Vg_Agri_Article.doc
CLASS ANALYSIS OF INDIAN AGRICULTURE
INDEX
- GROWTH OF COMMODITY PRODUCTIION
- Green Revokution
- Inputs
- Credit
- Output & productivity trends
- Utilisation of Surplus
B. DIFFERENTIATION OF THE PEASANTRY
1. Rural –Urban Divide
2. Agricultural Labour vs Kulak ?
3. Land-Holdings---- Land reforms- Tenancy
4. Household Industry
5. Home Market
- IMPACT ON THE SOCIAL RELATIONS OF PRODUCTION
**************************
……………….No doubt, a growth in “consumption” and “distribution” (i.e. growth in the home market) is an indication of the growth of capitalist relations in production but the important question is that what is its impact on production relations, and, even with this growth of commodity production which of the two modes of production (i.e., capitalist and feudal) is predominant in Indian agriculture ? This can only be done by taking an overall picture of production relations and not merely by picturing the growth in “consumption” and “distribution”. Lenin has said, “that the economists who have discoursed at length on the inadequate attention paid by the classical economists to ‘distribution’ and ‘consumption’ have not been able to give the slightest explanation of the most fundamental problems of ‘distribution’ and ‘consumption’. That is understandable, for one cannot even discuss ‘consumption’ unless one understands the process of the reproduction of the total social capital and of the replacement of the various parts of the social product... It is not with ‘production’ that political economy deals, but with the social relations of men in production, with the social system of production. Once these social relations have been analysed, the place in production of every class, and consequently, the share they get of the national consumption is thereby defined.” (Development of Capitalism in
Capitalism does not merely entail commodity production. As Lenin has said, “Capitalism is commodity production at its highest stage of development, when labour power itself becomes a commodity.” (Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism…. Lenin) Besides, when the CRC, Communist League, etc., speak of increasing “consumption” and “distribution” they forget Marx’s basic theory of realisation which states that : “According to the general law of capitalist production, constant capital grows faster than variable capital” and that “capitalist production, and, consequently, the home market, grow not so much on account of articles of consumption as on account of the means of production. In other words, the increase in means of production outstrips the increase in articles of consumption.” (Development of Capitalism in
While analysing the mode of production in Indian agriculture it is necessary to do so based on the laws of capitalist production as discovered by Marx and further developed by Lenin. These scientific laws of capitalism and imperialism are not time bound. They neither get out-dated nor change from country to country. The conditions may change in time and space but the basic laws of capitalism and imperialism remain unchanged. To understand the mode of production in
Regarding the question of capitalism in agriculture an important principle outlined by Lenin was that, “it is the development of capitalism in the manufacturing industry that is the main force which gives rise to, and develops, capitalism in agriculture.”
Also, while talking of the transformation of pre-capitalist forms of production to capitalism, Lenin has said that :
“the socialisation of labour by capitalism is manifested in the following process :
Firstly, the very growth of commodity production destroys the scattered condition of small economic units that is characteristic of natural economy and draws together the small local markets into an enormous national (and then world) market. Production of oneself is transferred into production for the whole of society: and the greater the development of capitalism, the stronger becomes the contradiction between this collective character of production and individual character of appropriation.
Secondly, capitalism replaces the former scattered production by an unprecedented4d concentration both in agriculture and in industry.
Thirdly, capitalism eliminates the forms of personal dependence that constituted on inalienable component of preceding systems of economy ...
Fourthly, capitalism necessarily creates mobility of the population, something not required by previous systems of social economy and impossible under them on anything like a large scale.
Fifthly, capitalism constantly reduces the proportion of the population engaged in agriculture and increases the number of large industrial centres.
Sixthly, capitalist society increases the population’s need for association, for organisation, and lends these organisations a character distinct from those of former times. While breaking down the narrow, local social-estate associations of medieval society and creating fierce competition, capitalism at the same time splits the whole society into large groups of persons occupying different positions in production and gives a tremendous impetus to organisation within each such group.
Seventhly, all the above mentioned changes effected in the old economic system by capitalism inevitably lead also to a change in the mentality of the population. The spasmodic character of economic development, the rapid transformation of the methods of production and the enormous concentration of production, the disappearance of all forms of personal dependence and patriarchalism in relationships, the mobility of population, the influence of the big industrial centres, etc., all this cannot but lead to a profound change in the very character of the producers.” (Development of Capitalism in
While studying the relations of production in Indian agriculture we will examine it under two heads : a) Growth of Commodity Production, and b) Disintegration of the peasantry.
A. GROWTH OF COMMODITY PRODUCTION
The growth of commodity production in agriculture can be assessed by the extent of utilisation of inputs and the growth of outputs produced for the market. The ‘green revolution’, which was introduced by the World Bank in
1) Green Revolution ………………………..
2) Inputs
Though irrigation may have increased, out of the 350 million acres of net cropped area, barely 50 million acres, or 14%, is cultivated more than once a year (VI Five Year Plan figures). If one crop takes on an average four months, 86% of
But besides the modernisaation, the number of wooden ploughs increased from 37.5 million in 1956 to 43 million in 1966 and further to 44.5 million (i.e. during the green revolution period) in 1972
3. Credit
From Table VI it can be seen that till 1978 as much as 71% of the population depended on non-institutional credit - on money-lenders, traders, landlords, etc.
It is thus clear that the stranglehold of usurious capital still dominates all sections of the rural populace. But usurious is an indication of pre-capitalist, feudal relations of production, which sucks up the surplus and prevents it from seeking productive channels. Besides, this usurious capital is increasing day by day. Marx has said that, “Usurer’s capital as the characteristic form of interest bearing capital corresponds to the predominance of small scale production of the self-employed peasant and small master craftsman”, “Usury centralises money wealth where the means of production are dispersed. It does not alter the mode of production, but attaches itself firmly to it like a parasite and makes it wretched. It sucks out its blood, enervates it and compels reproduction to proceed under even more pitiable conditions.” (Karl Marx, Vol. III, Chapter 36, pp594)
…………..Also with a large section of the peasantry having turned to HYV, (and now unable to turn back to the traditional varieties) and caught in a crisis with diminishing returns for their output, the peasants are dependent on large capital inputs each year which they are now unable to finance. This is forcing them to seek larger and larger loans. With the peasantry unable to even pay their interest on their cooperative loans, they are turning more and more back to the moneylender. This trend is bound to increase enormously in the coming years as the crisis in agriculture deepens.
4. Output and Productivity trends
In fact, the annual rate of growth of production of all agricultural crops actually dropped in the second period; while it was 3.2% in the 1951-52 to 1964-65 period, it was just 2.6% in the 1964-65 to 1983-84 period. This was because the increase in area under crops increased phenomenally in the first period at an annual rate of 1.7%, while in the second period the annual increase was just 0.4%. In other words, much better results in agricultural production could have been achieved by increasing the area under cropping than by introducing HYV.
The economic and scientific research foundation has estimated that soil erosion and deforestation has been so acute that
Generally, it can be summed up that production and yield of cropping has increased, with small increase towards cash crops, indicating some growth in capitalist relations. This is indicated through the change in some pockets of agriculture to capitalist farming and growth in commodity relations in large tracts of semi-feudal production, which continue their semi-feudal existence with enhanced contradictions caused by this lopsided growth of commodity relations within it. Productivity trends continue to indicate a backward mode of production with large farms being the least productive. Also with the increase in value of output being nowhere commensurate with the increase in value of inputs, it is clear that the growth in commodity production is lopsided, with this growth merely facilitating the dumping of commodities of the imperialists and comprador big bourgeoisie into the rural sector without significant returns to the farmer. This has led to a new set of contradictions in agriculture which are bound to intensify.
5) Utilisation of Surplus
This, in fact, is one of the factors in the determination of capitalist growth, as a fundamental law of capitalism is that constant capital (i.e., production of means of production) must grow at an increasingly fast rate. Therefore, in capitalist farming the kulak must reinvest his surplus in the farm in improved technology. Thereby he would increase the productivity of his farm and the surplus value extracted from it.
Besides this low generation of surplus in agriculture, even that generated goes primarily to other spheres. With the return on money-lending and trading far more profitable, a large proportion of this surplus is not re-invested in agriculture, instead finds its way in such spheres of activity. In fact, as long as usury continues to dominate the countryside as a most profitable sphere of investment, it will restrict the growth of capitalist development. Of course, with the inception of the ‘green revolution’ things have somewhat changed; but the limited extent to which it has generated capitalist farming can be seen from the poor levels of capital investment in agriculture taken as a whole.
Also ‘capital goods’ imports into the rural areas also began to increase, though at a much slower rate, in the same period.
SUMMARY
From the entire section on the growth of commodity production it will be seen that this growth is definite .... whether in the sphere of inputs, outputs, credits utilisation of surplus - all sections have to some extent been affected, thereby having an impact on the production relations in the rural economy. But the question is to what extent has it been able to change the relations of production in agriculture to capitalist ? To get a comprehensive answer to this question it is necessary to analyse the differentiation of the peasantry and all its related aspects. Meanwhile, it must be remembered that even by 1971-1972 only roughly 35% of grain production actually comes into the market. The bulk, over 65%, is consumed by the peasantry without ever reaching the market. This proportion of marketed grains has not changed perceptively in the last decade.
B. DIFFERENTIATITION OF THE PEASANTRY
The differentiation of the peasantry means the break up of the rural populace into a rural bourgeoisie and a rural proletariat. Lenin has said that for Russia, “two main lines of its development and outcome are objectively possible : either the old landlord economy, bound as it is by thousands of threads of serfdom, is retained and turns slowly into purely capitalist, ‘junker’ economy. The basis of the final transition from labour service to capitalism is the internal metamorphosis of feudalist landlord economy. The entire agrarian system of the state becomes capitalist and for a long time retains feudalist features. Or the old landlord economy is broken up by revolution, which destroys all the relics of serfdom, and large land ownership in the first place. The basis of the final transition from labour service to capitalism is the free development of small peasant farming, which has received a tremendous impetus as a result of the expropriation of the landlord estates in the interests of the peasantry. The entire agrarian system becomes capitalist, for the more completely the vestiges of serfdom are destroyed the more rapidly does the differentiation of the peasantry proceed.” (Preface to the II edition of Development of Capitalism in
To do so (ie. examine the differentiation of the peasantry and the growth of commodity production resulting from it) we will analyse it under the following sub-heads :
1) Rural-Urban Divide,
2) Agricultural Labour Vs. Kulak
3) Land Holding-Land Reforms
4) Household Industry
5) Home Market
1. Rural-Urban Divide
Lenin has said that, “the development of commodity economy means the divorcement of an ever-growing part of the population from agriculture, i.e., the growth of the industrial population at the expense of the agricultural population.” In explaining the entire process, Marx clarifies, “it is in the nature of capitalist production to continually reduce the agricultural population as compared to the non-agricultural, because in industry the increase of constant capital in relation to variable capital goes hand in hand with an absolute increase, though relative decrease, in variable capital, on the other hand in agriculture the variable capital required for the exploitation of certain plot of land decreases absolutely; it can thus only increase to the extent that new land is taken into cultivation, but this again requires as a pre-requisite a still great growth of the non-agricultural population.”
2. Agricultural Labourers vs Kulaks
Also, the productivity of farm workers in
So though a greater number of the peasantry may be disposed from the means of production and land and though wage labour may have increased with the ‘green revolution’, the bulk of the labour does not take on the form of regular free wage labour. So the clear differentiation of a rural proletariat and a rural bourgeoisie is yet to coalesce, except in few pockets. The result will be greater amount of labour turning into a commodity coupled withy further impoverishment of the peasantry. Yet this sale of labour power will more take the form of simple commodity production rather than capitalist production. For, say, a middle peasant is unable to carry out his farming operations with family labour and so hires three to four workers during the season.
Yet, if the bulk of the produce his family consumes, his exploitation of wage labour gives him no surplus value and so takes the form of simple commodity production even if his produce is a cash crop - say cotton. Much of the labour power sold in the Indian countryside takes this form, and though because of it commodity production expands, the home market grows and there is some change in agrarian relations, but fundamentally it takes the form of simple commodity production with a growth of small-scale farming without generating capitalism or a rural bourgeoisie. Also, it will be observed that labour-service in the form of share cropping and family cooperation co-exist and continue together with the emerging wage-labour system in Indian agriculture.
As regards the extent of growth of the rural bourgeoisie (Kulak) only a general picture can be got from the extent of capital formation in agriculture and the extent of the absorption of the means of production in agriculture. These various estimations are given in other sections. The particular extent of its existence can only be ascertained by specific area studies. The following are some general guidelines to assess whether a farmer comes within the category of rural bourgeoisie or continues as a rich peasant-landlord.
a) The bulk of the surplus must be extracted by the exploitation of labour power. He must employ more wage labour than the labour of his family.
b) The major part of the surplus value generated must be utilised in developing the means of production (machinery) and not in usury, trading, purchase of land, etc.
c) Labour power used must be free wage labour and the labourer should be divorced from the instruments of production - i.e., the implements for working should not be brought by the labourer, but instead provided by the owner of the farm. Payment should be in cash and not in kind.
d) The capitalist farmer must not give his land on rent, on the contrary, he may lease in land.
e) The capitalist farmer must produce for sale. So that bulk of his produce must be sold in the market and not consumed by him and his family.
f) The capitalist farmer should produce for profit - i.e., he must accumulate capital continuously. He must plan his production in such a manner that it enhances profit through agricultural operations.
By taking these six criteria into account we can roughly estimate the class character of the farmer - whether he belongs to the category of rural bourgeoisie or rich peasant-landlord class. Studies may show that a large number of such farmers may be found more to be in a transitional stage not having fully coalesced into a rural bourgeoisie and thereby meeting only some of the above mentioned six criteria.
3) Land holdings - land reforms
A full ten years after the so-called ‘green revolution’ the state of operational holdings in the country remained basically the same. Table XVII (see overleaf), gives a picture of operational holdings in 1976-77.
Firstly, Table XVII shows extensive parcellisation of the land where 10.7% of the cultivable land (of 17.6 million hectares) is distributed amongst 44.5 million holdings (families) of under one hectare each………. Besides, this fragmentation is continuing with the average size of holdings having dropped from 2.28 to 2 hectares between 1970-71 and 1976-77. But this is not all very rare is that a peasant has his entire plot in one contiguous area. In fact, the bulk of the plots are further fragmented, with each plot being divided into a number of small parcels which can vary from anything from 2 to 10 parcels of land per plot.
The estimated minimum number of agricultural plots in
This enormous fragmentation of land is an indication of a most backward mode of production and retards the growth of capitalist relations. Marx has said that, “small landed property pre-supposes that the overwhelming majority of the population is rural, and that not social but isolated labour predominates; and that, therefore, under such conditions wealth and development of reproduction, both of its material and spiritual pre-requisites, are out of question, and thereby also the pre-requisites for rational cultivation.” Marx adds that, “proprietorship of land parcels by its very nature excludes the development of social productive forces of labour, social forms of labour, social concentration of capital, large-scale cattle-raising and the progressive application of science.”
So this parcellisation and fragmentation of land is continuing apace, and if, within it, a certain amount of commodity production has been introduced with the help of HYV, cooperative loans, etc., it can lead to only simple commodity production and not capitalist relations of production.
Thus it will be seen that the main trend in agricultural land holding is continuing concentration of land in the hands of a few coupled with extensive small-scale farming. In between lie a class of rich peasantry (15-25 acres) who comprise 3.4% of the households and own 16.2% of land whose number has remained virtually static over the years. It is this section that has, of late, been more vocal as a result of ‘green revolution.’
This exposes the glaring existence of labour service in Indian agriculture. The continuing prevalence of tenancy, share-cropping, etc., is a further indication of the perseverance of feudal mode of production.
The estimates of cash rent and rent-in-king may not be too accurate and estimates vary from study to study. Other estimates put the rent-in-kind around 25%. But, one important point is that the content of the rent, whether in cash or kind, takes the form of pre-capitalist rent and not capitalist rent, as it involves distribution of surplus product and not of surplus value. The very tenancy acts themselves fix the proportion of distribution of the product between the landlord and serf. If it was to be capitalist rent the distribution would be assessed on the profit generated and not on the basis of the whole product.
4) Household Industry
Caste-based hereditary labour, according to the 1971 Census, increased over that of 1961 and stood at : barbers 7.11 lakhs, dhobies 9.47 lakhs, fishermen 6.01 lakhs, weavers and spinners 34.03 lakhs, shoemakers 5.97 lakhs, carpenters 12.64 lakhs, blacksmiths 10 lakhs, jewelry and precious metal workers (incl. goldsmiths) 5.76 lakhs, masons 15.35 lakhs, potters 9.66 lakhs, and tanners 0.53 lakhs.
If capitalist industry were to grow and break feudal relations it should first and foremost oust these ancient and backward forms of production and service. But these continue to co-exist, and even expand together with industrial growth. Also a differentiation of the peasantry would simultaneously see the collapse of the household sector, coupled with the growth of modern indigenous industry. Lenin has said that, “Domestic industries are a necessary adjunct of natural economy, remnants of which are nearly always retained where there is a small peasantry.” (Development of Capitalism in
In
Table XIX (see overleaf) which gives a picture of Khadi and Village Industries in India and their trend, indicates that the maximum growth in KVICs took place in the decade of the 1970s. Surprisingly this was the same period when capitalist relations grew fastest.
The continued existence and growth of this household sector is a clear indication of a backward pre-capitalist mode of production wherein over three million families (or three per cent of the population) continue their existence as artisans.
5) Home market
The differentiation of the peasantry will lead to an expansion of the home market.
In India, as already mentioned, though there has been a continuous increase in food grain production, the percentage finding its way into the market has been static at around 30% to 35%…………………A more recent estimate put that no more than the top 10% of th land-owning peasant household has able to produce marketable surpluses on any scale.
Also it will be found that the gross domestic capital formation as a percentage of the total has been virtually static in the decade of 1970s. It increased from 18% of the total (compared to registered manufacturing of 20%) in 1970-71 to 19% of the total (compared to registered manufacturing of 24%) in 1980-81. With little growth in percentage of capital formation in the rural areas it would reflect little growth in capitalist relations there during that period.
Another estimate of the growth in the rural market and of capitalism can be gauged by tracing the flow of commodities from urban to rural areas - and that too specifically in the sphere of production.
Table XX shows that, except for the early 1950s, in the entire period prior to the ‘green revolution’ there was a net flow of commodities from rural to urban areas, indicating a highly stagnant rural economy. From the ‘green revolution’ period this process was reversed and there has been a successively increasing net inflow of commodities into the rural areas indicating a growth in the rural market. No doubt, in the earlier year this growth was quite large - in 1967-68 it was Rs. 390 crore, which increased to Rs. 784 crore in 1970-71.
…………..This factor is also observable from the fact that the percentage of producer goods to consumer goods (which consists mostly of necessities like salt, tea, etc.) imported into rural areas jump-ed from 17% in 1967-68 to 25% in 1970-71 - indicating thereby a larger inflow of intermediary producer goods (like fertilisers, pesticides, etc.) primarily and also a small quantity of means of production (called capital goods in the Table XX) like farm machinery.
Also, during the entire period of the 1950s and 1960s there was a massive shrinking of the percentage of per capita consumer expenditure spent on industrial goods in the rural areas (and also urban areas). In other words there was a relative shrinking of the home market in that period with a larger and larger amount of the families’ incomes being devoted to the necessities of life. There was a perceptible reversal of this process in the rural areas from 1968-69 indicating some growth of market from the time of the ‘green revolution.’
SUMMARY
This entire section shows that there has been a very slight differentiation of the peasantry. The basic forms of pre-capitalist production relations has remained intact, with land concentration continuing as before and small scale petty farming dominating the bulk of the rural population. It is within this existing framework that commodity production and the agrarian market has been increased by the imperialists through the ‘green revolution’, thereby enhancing capitalist relations within the semi-feudal framework.
Thus, from this section we find that the ‘green revolution’ period has definitely witnessed a rise in commodity production. This is reflected in :
a growth of the urban population, growth of the rural market,
growth of banking and institutional finance in the rural areas,
a slight increase in constant capital in agriculture,
the widespread prevalence of HYV types, and a slight growth in productivity.
But at the same time all the pre-capitalist institutions continue to co-exist, if not increase. So we find,
no change in land holdings and the growth of backward small scale farming,
the traditional wooden and iron ploughs and bullock carts continued,
widespread prevalence of household industry,
the bulk of foodgrain production still being produced for consumption and not for market,
the bulk of the surplus still not going to increase constant capital but for usury, trading, etc.
no scientific utilisation of agriculture with productivity decreasing with increasing size of farm,
the continuing prevalence of tenancy, share-cropping, etc.
the bulk of the population continuing to be dependent on land,
little differentiation of the peasantry with little growth in the agricultural labour,
With the labour generated continuing to be not free labour but attached and that which is free labour is being more of a seasonal type, and
the continuing caste-based division of labour of handicrafts and services.
It is clear from this that the growth in capitalist relations has merely been super-imposed on the existing semi-feudal structure and has not proceeded to smash it.
No doubt, this increased capitalist penetration will enhance the contradictions within the rural economy, undermining to some extent traditional feudal relations and have its own impact on the class antagonisms in the countryside. One effect of this has been the mass upsurges of the middle and rich peasantry in many HYV areas. Though also some pockets of bourgeois farming will have developed (its limit can be seen in the excessively low increase in constant capital and particularly of the means of production, within Indian agriculture taken as a whole) the major impact of the ‘green revolution’ has been to enhance simple commodity production and not capitalist production.
Simple commodity production has existed since slave society, while capitalism, as already mentioned, “is commodity production at its highest stage of development, when labour power itself becomes a commodity.” Simple commodity production is present when constant capital remains static with little or no surplus value being generated with the bulk of the produce being utilised to sustain the person and his family. Capitalist production, on the other hand, entails a continuing increase in constant capital and a generation of surplus value which is utilised to enhance the means of production.
So, whether it is a petty farmer, utilising even some limited wage labour, or whether it is a handicrafts man or some household industry, or whether it may be any other petty producer - they may all produce commodities but neither do they generate surplus value not do they develop or increase constant capital. This form of simple commodity production can continue for generations with out having much impact on the social relations of production. Capitalist production, on the other hand, revolutionises the mode of production and by a continuous increase of the constant capital leads to the ruination and destruction of the small producer. The primary impact of the ‘green revolution’, except developing a rural bourgeoisie in certain pockets, has led to the growth of simple commodity production on the lakhs of small fragmented farms through the widespread utilisation of HYV.
Also, the enhancement in sale of labour power utilised in simple commodity production may extend the market but will not be a measure of the growth of capitalist relations. In
Finally, it is manufacturing industry that is the main force which develops capitalism in agriculture. Though industry has been growing, it has been doing so as an off-shoot of finance capital and therefore has been unable to generate that employment that is necessary to absorb any differentiation of the peasantry that may take place in the countryside. So the growth of the manufacturing industry within the imperialist framework, has not acted as that force to develop capitalism in agriculture. On the contrary, we have seen, as with the house hold industry, it even allies itself with the pre-capitalist sectors of production. The result of such warped industrial growth is a massive unemployment in the urban areas together with even larger under-employment in the rural areas.
Thus, the overall agrarian picture in
C. IMPACT ON SOCIAL RELATIONS OF PRODUCTION
To sum up, the chief characteristics of the present day rural
a) Fragmentation of agricultural land and in consequence the predominance of small scale agriculture and subsistence farming,
b) Leasing out of land by deeds and by word of mouth for the performance of labour service, i.e., tenancy, share cropping, etc.
c) Primitive instruments of production
d) Prevalence of caste and hereditary division of labour
e) Preponderance of household industry
f) Continuance of household industry
g) Limited growth of market with bulk of food grains maintained for consumption and much payment in kind.
h) Attachment of the overwhelming proportion of the population to land.
i) Limited differentiation of the peasantry
j) Growth of commodity circulation on a small scale, and
k) Continuation of the patriarchal family, caste relations and diverse personal dependence.
That is, a continuation of the semi-feudal mode of production with an enhanced amount of commodity circulation within it resulting in some growth of capitalist relations. The main impact has been to enhance simple commodity production and create pockets of a rural bourgeoisie within a predominantly semi-feudal structure.
Its impact on the social relations of production have been :
1) To reduce the traditional feudal methods of oppression,
2) To create a powerful rich peasant section
3) With HYV to force vast sections of the rural population into market
4) To further perpetuate the fragmentation and parcellisation of land thereby increasing the poor and middle peasant population enormously.
5) To greatly impoverish the landless, poor and even middle peasants, forcing them to sell their labour power in order to eke out an existence
6) Greater imperialist loot of the entire rural population leading to a crisis in the agriculture with a continuing reduction in surplus being generated (i.e., after the first decade of ‘green revolution’)
7) To a growth of simple commodity production and small pockets of rural bourgeoisie
8) To a continuation of all the other feudal forms of exploitation, viz., usury, trading, etc.
The result of this has been to enhance the contradictions within agriculture :
i) Due to further impoverishment, heightening the contradiction between the landless and poor peasants on the one hand and the rich peasants and landlords on the other,
ii) With vast sections being brought under HYV and within the market, and with the value of output dropping and fluctuating enormously with fluctuations in weather and fluctuations in the market - i.e., a crisis situation developing, an increased contradiction with this vast masses and the imperialist-comprador bourgeoisie and government.
iii) With the accumulation of certain wealth by the rich peasants and a section of landlords due to the ‘green revolution’ the growth of more powerful and vocal rich peasant lobby, and
iv) With the crisis of the ‘green revolution’ due to high prices of inputs and a falling price of outputs a growing contradiction between the rich peasantry, a section of landlords (who have taken to HYV) and the middle peasantry on the one hand and the government, imperialism and comprador big bourgeoisie on the other.
So good topic really i like any post talking about Ancient Greece but i want to say thing to u Ancient Greece not that only ... you can see in Ancient Greece Chiefs and People and more , you shall search in Google and Wikipedia about that .... thanks a gain ,,,
ReplyDelete